Empty Homes, Longer Commutes: Effects of more Restrictive Local Planning
We have argued for a very long time that the fundamental problem with housing in Britain is a lack of supply: we have been underbuilding for two generations.
We have argued for a very long time that the fundamental problem with housing in Britain is a lack of supply: we have been underbuilding for two generations. Updating the simple estimate one of us made in 2014, the building shortfall in England just since 1994 has risen from about 2m homes to 2.5m. Moreover, it seems that we go on building the wrong sort of houses in the wrong places. Over the past 15 years, for example, we built more than twice as many houses per person in low-demand areas like Doncaster and Barnsley than in Oxford and Cambridge.
In the pursuit of ‘urban density’ and ‘building on Brownfields’ we build too many cramped flats and maisonettes in less attractive cities or city neighbourhoods but almost no family friendly homes with gardens within reach of high paying jobs. We are spending £18bn on CrossRail— but once it gets over the Green Belt boundary can build no houses. There is a price to pay for building on Brownfields and not allocating enough land: a crisis of affordability and a hugely inequitable transfer of housing assets to the rich and the old. Our housing crisis is a long-term crisis of supply: an endemic lack of supply interacting with rising demand.
One of the many arguments used for allocating less land for housing is ‘all those vacant homes’. Even one of the least restrictive English Regions, the East Midlands, argued in their Regional Spatial Strategy that they could allocate less land because they assumed they would reduce housing vacancies by 0.5 percentage points (that is, by about 12.5% of the long term average). Islington Council moved to use the planning system to tackle the ‘scandal of empty homes’ in 2014.
A logically equivalent assertion was made by Lord Rogers, the longstanding advocate of urban density, in arguing against allowing offices to be converted to housing to help with London’s housing supply: ‘…why should we rush to convert office blocks when we already have three-quarters of a million homes in England lying empty…?.
The trouble with interventions in the housing market is that, however well-intentioned, they often generate all sorts of unintended consequences. Markets respond by generating new and sometimes perverse incentives. Reflecting this, one of our most recent research findings, just published in the Journal of Public Economics, is that more restrictive local planning actually has the net effect of increasing the proportion of vacant homes.
Having fewer empty houses is in itself a good thing. We have a shortage of houses and using the stock more intensively is a way of increasing efficiency. That is just how cut-price airlines operate: they keep their seats full and their aircraft in the air. But they do not just assume planes will spend more of their lives in the air and seats will be fuller. They have an analysis of how to achieve this.
Unless we understand why houses are vacant, we cannot rationally hope to reduce the numbers that are empty just by being more restrictive. It would come as no surprise to economists to observe that in well-functioning labour markets there was unemployment. Workers search for jobs and employers seek (better) qualified workers. Attempting to regulate unemployment away makes no sense. Vacant houses are equivalent to unemployed workers, so it makes no more sense to try to ‘regulate’ vacancies away. That does not, of course, mean that we should not have policies to try to minimise their number (what those policies should be is material for another blog).
What really happens if, by tightening planning restrictiveness (saying ‘no’ to more development proposals), a Local Authority makes housing even scarcer? Well, on the one hand it will make housing in its area more expensive. This will increase the incentives to occupy housing, so reduce vacancies.
Unfortunately, more restrictive planning also makes it harder to modify homes or build new ones in different places or with different features to adapt the characteristics of the housing stock to the constantly changing patterns of demand. Jobs grow in a locality, so demand for houses there increases; the local school gets better so the demand for family-sized homes increases; people buy a car, so want parking, a garage; they have fewer children or separate, so they want smaller homes— the list is potentially endless. The result of this is that in more restrictive locations people wanting a home find it more difficult to match their preferences to what is available. So they have to search longer or further afield. The result of that is there are more empty houses in the more tightly regulated places and more people living and commuting from the less regulated places further afield. Both this ‘mismatch’ and the price effects work at the same time but in opposite directions. So which dominates is an empirical question.
In our paper we go to great lengths to deal with problems of reverse causation and endogeneity. We have 30 years of data for 350 English Local Authorities; the results of our analysis show with substantial reliability that the net effect of more local restrictiveness is not just to increase the proportion of empty homes but to increase it substantially. A one standard deviation increase in local restrictiveness causes the local vacancy rate to increase by nearly a quarter. That is not all. Because it makes finding a suitable house locally more difficult, it also increases the average distance people have to travel to work. The same increase in local restrictiveness causes a 6.1 percent rise in commuting distances.
So attempting to regulate housing vacancies away by allocating less land or being more restrictive with respect to new building or adaptation of existing structures, in fact increases the proportion of local homes that are empty as well making people who work in the area commute further. This is of course the absolute opposite of what the advocates of the policy want to achieve.
It is the mismatch between the preferences of households and the housing stock on offer that leads, other things equal, to higher vacancy rates in the more regulated— typically more desirable— places. Such constraints will likely cause a significant welfare loss. This is because too much housing stays empty in the most regulated, most desirable and, by implication, most productive places with the strongest demand and highest valuations for living space. People are thus induced to commute further, while living in the “wrong” places.
The policy lesson would seem to be that planners should not allocate less land for development on the grounds that there are empty houses; nor should they make it more difficult to build or adapt houses. Rather, they should encourage more flexibility with the number, location and type of houses.
There is, moreover, a nice irony for advocates of the ‘compact city’. The most common policy to attempt to implement this ideal is to impose growth boundaries, making land scarcer, and is implemented via Green Belts in Britain. Such policies also imply more restrictiveness with respect to adaptations of the existing stock or new construction in the areas in the Green Belts or beyond the containment boundary. Aiming for a compact city, in other words, makes planning policy more restrictive. Our results show this will have exactly the opposite to the intended effect because average commuting distances will lengthen as residents search further afield for housing they can afford and more closely matches their preferences.